State intervention in land pricing and endogenous risk aversion

Authors

DOI:

https://doi.org/10.58567/jea02040004

Keywords:

land pricing, stochastic discount factor, land taxation, the Lucas critique, endogenous risk aversion

Abstract

This study explores the cause and effect of endogenous risk aversion in land pricing, where state intervention through taxation remains a general practice. Using a consumption-based asset pricing model incorporating taxation, it is shown that high taxation, due to the indexation effect, supporting land prices and reducing individuals' risk expectations, could lead to an endogenous decrease in risk aversion, which could result in market dysfunction because risk aversion plays a key role in the market mechanism. China, with its wholly state-owned land and the general use of land sales to cover financial deficits, is a typical case for empirical tests. The tests confirm that there, the rise in land prices was driven by the increase in reserve prices set by local governments, a strong means of taxation, and not by the market, indicating the endogenous decrease in risk aversion.

References

Alchian, A. A. & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62, 777-95. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1815199

Arrow, K. J. (1965). The theory of risk aversion, Helsinki: Yrjo Jahnssonin Saatio, Reprinted in: Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing, Chicago: Markham Publ. Co., 1971, 90–109.

Barry, P. J. (1980). Capital asset pricing and farm real estate. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(3), 549-553. https://doi.org/10.2307/124021

Begley, T. M. & Boyd, D. P. (1987). Psychological characteristics associated with performance in entrepreneurial firms and smaller businesses. Journal of Business Venturing, 2(1), 79-93. https://doi.org/10.1016/0883-9026(87)90020-6

Bellemare, M. F. & Brown, Z. S. (2010). On the (mis) use of wealth as a proxy for risk aversion. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 92(1), 273–82. https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1093/ajae/aap006

Berardi, M. (2016), Endogenous time-varying risk aversion and asset returns. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26(3), 581–601. https://DOI: 10.1007/s00191-015-0435-3

Bird, R. M. & Slack, E. (2002). Land and property taxation around the world: a review. Journal of Property Tax Assessment and Administration, 7(3), 31-80.

Breeden, D. T. (1979). An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and investment. Journal of Financial Economics, 7, 265–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(79)90016-3

Buchanan, J. M. & Tullock, G. (1962). The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.

Caliendo, M., Fossen, F. & Kritikos, A. (2010). The impact of risk attitudes on entrepreneurial survival. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 76(1), 45-63. https://DOI:10.1016/j.jebo.2010.02.012

Callen, M., Isaqzadeh, M., Long, J. D. & Sprenger, C. (2014). Violence and risk preference: Experimental evidence from Afghanistan. American Economic Review, 104(1), 123-48. https://DOI: 10.1257/aer.104.1.123

Campbell, J. Y. & Cochrane, J. H. (1999). By force of habit: a consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 107, 205–51. https://doi.org/10.1086/250059

Capozza, D.R. & Schwarm, G. (1989). The asset approach to pricing urban land: Some empirical results. AREUEA Journal, 17(2), 161–175. http://hdl.handle.net/2027.42/75058

Chavas, J. P. & Thomas, A. (1999). A dynamic analysis of land prices. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81(4), 772-784. https://doi.org/10.2307/1244323

Chinese Ministry of Land and Resources, Chinese Land and Resources Statistical Yearbook, 2000~2015, Beijing: Geological Press Edition.

Chouquer, G. (2011). Aspects and characteristics of State-owned land in West Africa. Land Tenure and Development, Technical Committee, January 2011, AGTER, http://www.agter.org/bdf/en /corpus_chemin/fiche-chemin-147.

Cochrane, J. H. (2005). Asset Pricing. Revised edition, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

Constantinides, G. M. (1990). Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 519–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261693

Dai, Q. & Singleton, K. J. (2000). ‘Specification analysis of affine term structure models. Journal of Finance, 55, 1943–78. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00278

Department of Urban Socio-economic Surveys (National Bureau of Statistics of China), China City Statistical Yearbook. 2000~2015, Beijing: China Statistics Press.

Dohmen, T., Lehmann, H. & Pignatti, N. (2016). Time-varying individual risk attitudes over the Great Recession: A comparison of Germany and Ukraine. Journal of Comparative Economics, 44(1), 182-200. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2015.10.002

Fischel, W. A. (2001). Municipal corporations, homeowners and the benefit view of the property tax. In Property taxation and local government finance, Wallace E. Oates, ed., 33–77. Cambridge MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Görlitz, K. & Tamm, M. (2015). Parenthood and risk preferences, Available at SSRN 2618442.

Gould, W. W. (1992). Quantile regression with bootstrapped standard errors. Stata Technical Bulletin, sg11.1, 9: 19–21. Reprinted in Stata Technical Bulletin Reprints, 2, 137–39, College Station, TX: Stata Press.

Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. & Zingales L. (2018). Time varying risk aversion. Journal of Financial Economics, 128(3), 403-421. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2018.02.007

Hamilton, B. W. (1976). Capitalization of intrajurisdictional differences in local tax prices. American Economic Review, 66(5), 743–753. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1827488

Hanaoka, C., Shigeoka, H. & Watanabe, Y. (2018). Do risk preferences change? evidence from the great east japan earthquake. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 10(2), 298-330. https://DOI: 10.1257/app.20170048

Haushofer, J. & Fehr, E. (2014). On the psychology of poverty. Science, 344(6186), 862-867. https://DOI: 10.1126/science.1232491

Hayek, F. A. (1935). Socialist calculation I: the nature of the problem; Socialist calculation II: the state of the debate. in Hayek, 1976, Individualism and Economic Order, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

Hetschko, C. & Preuss, M. (2019). Income in Jeopardy: How losing employment affects the willingness to take risks. Journal of Economic Psychology. https://DOI: 10.1016/j.joep.2019.05.005

Holmström, B. & Tirole, J. (2001. LAPM: A liquidity‐based asset pricing model”, Journal of Finance, 56 (5), 1837-1867. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00391

Lange, O. (1936-1937). On the economic theory of socialism, part one”, Review of Economic Studies, Part one, 4(1), 53–71; Part two, 4(2), 123–42. http://hdl.handle.net/10.2307/2967609

Lerman, Z. & Shagaida, N. (2007). Land policies and agricultural land markets in Russia. Land Use Policy, 24, 14–23. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2006.02.001

Lucas, R. (1976). Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In Brunner, K. & Meltzer, A. eds. The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 1, 19–46, New York: American Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2231(76)80003-6

Malmendier, U. & Nagel, S. (2011). Depression babies: do macroeconomic experiences affect risk taking? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1), 373-416. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjq004

Mieszkowski, P. (1972). The property tax: An excise tax or a profits tax? Journal of Public Economics, 1 (1), 73–96. https://doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(72)90020-5

Necker, S. & Ziegelmeyer, M. (2016). Household risk taking after the financial crisis. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 59, 141-160. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2539016

Nieβ, C. & Biemann, T. (2014). The role of risk propensity in predicting self-employment. Journal of Applied Psychology, 99(5), 1000-1009. https://DOI:10.1037/a0035992

Pigou, A. C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare, 4th edition, London: Macmillan.

Pratt, J. W. (1964). Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica, 32(1–2), 122–136. https://doi.org/0012-9682(196401/04)32:1/2<122:RAITSA>2.0.CO;2-W

Pyle, W. (2009). Ownership and allocation of industrial land in Russia. Focus/Opinion, Expert view, 4/2009, Bank of Finland, Institute for Economies in Transition, (BOFIT).

Sahm, C. R. (2012). How much does risk tolerance change? The quarterly journal of finance, 2(04), 1-38. http://DOI:10.1142/S2010139212500206

Schildberg-Hörisch, H. (2018). Are risk preferences stable? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(2), 135-54. https://DOI: 10.1257/jep.32.2.135

Tiebout, Charles M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424. https://doi.org/10.1086/257839

Vincent, C. H., Hanson, L. A. & Argueta, C. N. (2017). Federal Land Ownership: Overview and Data. Congressional Research Service Report.

Weber, M., Weber, E. U. & Nosić, A. (2013). Who takes risks when and why: determinants of changes in investor risk taking. Review of Finance, 17(3), 847-883. https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfs024

Wickens M. (2011). Macroeconomic Theory, A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach. Second edition, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

Zodrow, G. R. & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). The new view of the property tax: A reformulation. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 16 (3), 309–327. https://doi.org/10.1016/0166-0462(86)90028-1

Downloads

Published

2023-06-20

How to Cite

He, Y. (2023). State intervention in land pricing and endogenous risk aversion. Journal of Economic Analysis, 2(4), 63–81. https://doi.org/10.58567/jea02040004

Issue

Section

Article